Rad Geek People's Daily

official state media for a secessionist republic of one

Posts from March 2022

Freedom Fries Overture

The Russian government’s ongoing war against Ukraine is, of course, awful and by all means ought to be denounced, opposed, if possible resisted.

This kind of thing, however, is not a sane or intelligent response to that, let alone an appropriate one.

Shared Article from Classical Music

Cardiff Philharmonic removes Tchaikovsky from programme in light…

The orchestra had an all-Tchaikovsky concert scheduled for next week, but has decided to change the programme having deemed it to be 'inappropriate' a…

classical-music.com


I suppose it will be ploddingly obvious to point out that the Russian government (which is not actually the government that was in place back in 1882 — although that other one, also, was a very, very bad militaristic government) is not the same thing of Russia as a people, or the entire history of modern Russian culture. But I will say that nevertheless, and the idea that a terrible war in Ukraine is a good reason to open up a second front in the orchestra pits against the menace of Russian concert overtures is hysterical, illiberal and would be alarmingly belligerent if it weren’t so goddamned self-importantly ridiculous.

(Link thanks to Jesse Walker.)

Cities Without States and Social Scale Without Social Control

What I’ve been reading: From the (generally really fascinating) first chapter on early cities in David Graeber and David Wengrow’s The Dawn of Everything: A New History of Humanity. Footnotes are from the text unless otherwise indicated. Boldface emphasis is mine.

Dunbar’s Number Is Just A Number:

In the standard, textbook version of human history, scale is crucial. The tiny bands of foragers in which humans were thought to have spent most of their evolutionary history could be relatively democratic and egalitarian precisely because they were small. It’s common to assume — and is often stated as self-evident fact — that our social sensibilities, even our capacity to keep track of names and faces, are largely determined by the fact that we spent 95 per cent of our evolutionary history in tiny groups of at best a few dozen individuals. We’re designed to work in small teams. As a result, large agglomerations of people are often treated as if they were by definition somewhat unnatural, and humans as psychologically ill equipped to handle life inside them. This is the reason, the argument often goes, that we require such elaborate ‘scaffolding’ to make larger communities work: such things as urban planners, social workers, tax auditors and police.[1]

If so, it would make perfect sense that the appearance of the first cities, the first truly large concentrations of people permanently settled in one place, would also correspond to the rise of states. For a long time, the archaeological evidence — from Egypt, Mesopotamia, China, Central America and elsewhere — did appear to confirm this. If you put enough people in one place, the evidence seemed to show, they would almost inevitably develop writing or something like it, together with administrators, storage and redistribution facilities, workshops and overseers. Before long, they would also start dividing themselves into social classes. **Civilization came as a package. It meant misery and suffering for some (since some would inevitably be reduced to serfs, slaves or debt peons), but also allowed for the possibility of philosophy, art and the accumulation of scientific knowledge.

The evidence no longer suggests anything of the sort. In fact, much of what we have come to learn in the last forty or fifty years has thrown conventional wisdom into disarray. In some regions, we now know, cities governed themselves for centuries without any sign of the temples and palaces that would only emerge later; in others, temples and palaces never emerged at all. In many early cities, there is simply no evidence of either a class of administrators or any other sort of ruling stratum. In others, centralized power seems to appear and then disappear. It would seem that the mere fact of urban life does not, necessarily, imply any particular form of political organization, and never did.

This has all sorts of important implications: for one thing, it suggests a much less pessimistic assessment of human possibilities, since the mere fact that much of the world’s population now live in cities may not determine how we live, to anything like the extent you might assume . . . .

— David Graeber and David Wengrow, The Dawn of Everything: A New History of Humanity. Chapter 8, Imaginary Cities, 277-278.

Two Conceptions of Equality; Heavy Lies the Head That Wears the Burden of Proof:

So far in this chapter we’ve looked at what happened when cities first appeared in three distinct parts of Eurasia. In each case, we noted the absence of monarchs or any evidence of a warrior elite, and the corresponding likelihood that each had instead developed institutions of communal self-governance. Within those broad parameters, each regional tradition was very different. Contrasts between the expansion of Uruk and the Ukrainian mega-sites illustrate this point with particular clarity.[2] Both appear to have developed an ethos of explicit egalitarianism — but it took strikingly different forms in each.

It is possible to express these differences at a purely formal level. A self-conscious ethos of egalitarianism, at any point in history, might take either of two diametrically opposing forms. We can insist that everyone is, or should be, precisely the same (at least in the ways that we consider important); or alternatively, we can insist that everyone is so utterly different from each other that there are simply no criteria for comparison (for example, we are all unique individuals, and so there is no basis upon which any one of us can be considered better than another). Real-life egalitarianism will normally tend to involve a bit of both.

Yet it could be argued that Mesopotamia — with its standardized household products, allocation of uniform payments to temple employees, and public assemblies — seems to have largely embraced the first version. Ukrainian mega-sites, in which each household seems to have developed its own unique artistic style and, presumably, idiosyncratic domestic rituals, embraced the second.[3] The Indus valley appears — if our interpretation is broadly correct — to represent yet a third possibility, where rigorous equality in certain areas (even the bricks were all precisely the same size) was complemented by explicit hierarchy in others.

It’s important to stress that we are not arguing that the very first cities to appear in any region of the world were invariably founded on egalitarian principles (in fact, we will shortly see a perfect counter-example). What we are saying is that archaeological evidence shows this to have been a surprisingly common pattern, which goes against conventional evolutionary assumptions about the effects of scale on human society. In each of the cases we’ve considered so far — Ukrainian mega-sites, Uruk Mesopotamia, the Indus valley — a dramatic increase in the scale of organized human settlement took place with no resulting concentration of wealth or power in the hands of ruling elites. In short, archaeological research has shifted the burden of proof on to those theorists who claim causal connections between the origins of cities and the rise of stratified states, and whose claims now look increasingly hollow.

— David Graeber and David Wengrow, The Dawn of Everything: A New History of Humanity. Chapter 8, Imaginary Cities, 321-322

  1. [1]1. E.g. Dunbar 1996; 2010.
  2. [2][This is rather too strong of a statement for the underlying evidence. Graeber and Wengrow’s extended discussion of the Ukrainian mega-sites is really interesting and suggestive, but also highly speculative, with lots of interesting but uncertain interpretation introduced entirely on the strength of the fact that the prehistoric dwellings are arranged in circles, and this would have a deep symbolic meaning in the similarly circular arrangement of modern Basque villages (288-297). Well, maybe; that’s a really interesting thought about how scale might be managed without central organization in a certain kind of settlement, and it ought to be investigated more if possible. But there’s an awful lot more that we can say with clarity and firm evidential grounding about the Uruk Expansion than we can about the Mega-Site settlements. —R.G.]
  3. [3]102. As argued in Wengrow 2015.

Who

Love Song

Sweep the house clean,
hang fresh curtains
in the windows
put on a new dress
and come with me!
The elm is scattering
its little loaves
of sweet smells
from a white sky!

Who shall hear of us
in the time to come?
Let him say there was
a burst of fragrance
from black branches.

— William Carlos Williams, Love Song
A Book of Poems: Al Que Quiere! (1917), 35.

Shared Article from Poetry Foundation

Love Song - Audio Poem of the Day | Poetry Foundation

By William Carlos Williams (read by Matthew Rohrer)

poetryfoundation.org


(William Carlos Williams wrote a whole bunch of poems around 1916-1917 entitled Love Song — there’s another one in the same book even, and the one published by Poetry in November 1916, which is linked from the Audio Poem of the Day page as the supposed text of the poem in the reading, is another, different poem from the one that was read. So it actually took me a minute to hunt down a good copy of the text for this after I heard it in audio form. This one appeared in A Book of Poems: Al Que Quiere! (1917), after the poem Summer Song and before Foreign.)

Against Legalization: California Politics and the Scourge of Local Control

Marijuana shouldn’t be illegal. Jesus. Of course it shouldn’t. And California voters approved the legal cultivation and sale of recreational marijuana five years ago in Fall 2016. This is, on the whole, obviously good, part of the sudden and increasingly rapid crumbling of failed prohibition policies in multiple states throughout the U.S. I’m glad it happened and as far as it goes, I hope it continues. But making weed a legal business in the state of California means that it is subject to a whole lot of business as usual in the state of California, and has produced results as ludicrous and stupid as they are appalling.

Here is an article on it by Scott Shackford, forthcoming in the April 2022 issue of Reason:

Shared Article from Reason.com

Corruption and Crackdowns in California's Marijuana Market

Black markets thrive under mismanaged legalization.

Scott Shackford @ reason.com


After California voters decided to legalize the cultivation and sale of recreational marijuana in 2016, the vast majority of the state’s cities banned those activities within their borders. But Adelanto’s leaders were eager to embrace the newly legal market. The small desert town of 31,000, best known for its nearby prisons, had a reputation for poverty and emptiness. . . . In May 2017, the Adelanto City Council approved a plan to license recreational growers and retailers, making the town one of the first in the state to do so. . . . In an interview with The New York Times, then-Mayor Richard Kerr predicted that Adelanto could raise $10 million annually by taxing local marijuana businesses.

It didn’t happen. Adelanto’s budget for 2020–21 anticipated just $1.4 million in marijuana revenue, less than a third of the city’s projected $4.5 million budget deficit. While that $1.4 million is money the town would not have seen without legalization, it clearly isn’t enough to save Adelanto.

Kerr is no longer Adelanto’s mayor. The FBI raided his home in 2018 as part of a corruption investigation. Three years later it arrested him on seven counts of wire fraud and two counts of bribery. Kerr is accused of taking at least $57,000 in bribes and kickbacks to approve permits for marijuana businesses. His arrest came four years after then–City Council Member Jermaine Wright was accused of taking a $10,000 bribe from an undercover FBI agent posing as an applicant seeking approval for a local marijuana transportation business.

Other local officials in California have been implicated in similar corruption . . . the Los Angeles Times implied that the problem was California’s “nascent, ill-regulated marijuana industry.”[1] Stories about California’s marijuana market commonly describe it as a Wild West situation.

It is true that California has badly mishandled legalization–so badly that, more than five years after voters approved that change, the black market still accounts for an estimated two-thirds of cannabis sales. But far from the result of weak regulation, the disastrous rollout of legal marijuana stems from giving officials too much power to decide who can produce and sell it….

— Scott Shackford, Corruption and Crackdowns in California’s Marijuana Market.
Reason (April 2022), 27-28. Boldface emphasis added.

California’s licensed legalization scheme has generally made it pretty easy and pretty lucrative for the large, incumbent medical cannabis businesses to expand into the legal recreational market, but it has also instituted an arbitrarily limited ration of permits and a burdensome, restrictive, and almost infinitely-delaying system of licenses, byzantine regulatory requirements and very expensive sin taxes and compliance costs.[2] Weed is legal throughout the state, and that’s great, but if you want to actually get set up to sell weed legally it involves waiting for years in priority queues for permits, raising hundreds of thousands or millions of dollars in capital, jumping through regulatory hopes which grant tremendous discretionary power to city governments and endless opportunities for your incumbent competitors to lock you out of the legal market; and which simply reinstitute blanket prohibition through NIMBY zoning and layer after layer of local control. Recreational weed was legalized five years ago; the City of Fresno, to take one example, set up a system of interviews and scoring which only approved its first legal dispensaries last Fall. Los Angeles has 217 licensed recreational weed shops for a population of 4 million people; they realized that their process was so slow it was effectively locking out the very people who had been disproportionately harmed by the old prohibitionist policies. So they created a social equity program that would help grease the wheels for disadvantaged and marginalized applicants — so far, it has helped to approve a grand total of 20 new storefront shops in three years. Outside of the largest cities and some regulatory oases like Adelanto, the vast majority of municipalities just don’t issue any licenses and prohibit weed shops entirely.)

All this legal control has produced some really spectacular gross corruption — which the conventionally-minded press then, wildly, blames on the insufficiency of industry regulation. (Of course it is exactly the opposite; the corruption cases were all about illicitly purchasing permits, privileges and anticompetitive exclusions that exist only because of the regulatory framework in the legalization law.) It also means that in the country’s biggest legal-weed state, two-thirds of the weed is still sold on the black market:

Most California cannabis consumers do not buy pot from state-licensed shops. Market observers such as Global Go Analytics estimate that illegal cannabis sales in California total $8 billion a year, double the amount of legal sales.

One reason for the black market’s persistence is that many Californians do not have easy access to legal retailers. California has only two licensed dispensaries for every 100,000 residents, compared to about 18 in Oregon and 14 in Colorado.

Proposition 64, the ballot initiative that legalized recreational marijuana, authorized municipalities to cap the number of local retailers or prohibit them entirely. For every California city that allows dispensaries, two have banned them.

While Prop. 64 allows people to grow their own marijuana, that alternative has little appeal for consumers who lack the requisite space, equipment, and know-how. In the parts of the state where retailers are banned, this policy is akin to letting people brew their own beer while denying them the ability to buy the finished product from a local store.

— Scott Shackford, Corruption and Crackdowns in California’s Marijuana Market.
Reason (April 2022), 28. Boldface emphasis added.

The State of California’s answer to this utterly inane and completely evitable situation has been to send in the cops again, increase enforcement, seize marijuana plants and arrest unlicensed operators. Incumbent operators in the United Cannabis Business Association loves this because the force of the state shuts down their competitors and protects the lifestyle to which they have become accustomed:

So far the government’s response to this marijuana mayhem has focused on tougher enforcement and penalties rather than lighter taxes and regulations. Prop. 64 authorized civil penalties against unlicensed marijuana growers and sellers, who also are guilty of misdemeanors punishable by a $500 fine and up to six months in jail. A law that took effect at the beginning of 2022 doubles down on that approach, allowing civil fines of up to $30,000 per violation against anyone guilty of aiding or abetting unlicensed cannabis commercial activity. Each day of assisting illegal sales or cultivation is a separate violation.

The Drug Policy Alliance and the American Civil Liberties Union opposed that law, warning that the wording is vague (it doesn’t define aiding and abetting) and will let local law enforcement target low-level employees, who could have their wages garnished and driver’s licenses suspended. But the United Cannabis Business Association welcomed the new penalties, saying the illicit cannabis market must be shut down to ensure that legal operators can see an increase of patients and consumers, which creates union jobs.

— Scott Shackford, Corruption and Crackdowns in California’s Marijuana Market.
Reason (April 2022), 31. Boldface emphasis added.

Gentlemen, that is all; you may now close up the State of California. It has finally reached its logical conclusion.

But yet, notwithstanding:

. . . In October, California Attorney General Rob Bonta bragged about a 13-week operation by state and local law enforcement officials that rounded up and eradicated more than 1 million illegally grown marijuana plants. The cops targeted growers who tried to escape oppressive fees, taxes, and licensing demands by operating in rural areas.

Raids like these were a familiar feature of life in California for decades before voters approved legalization. The difference now is that the government is promoting a black market not by banning marijuana but making its production and sale absurdly difficult to accomplish legally.

— Scott Shackford, Corruption and Crackdowns in California’s Marijuana Market.
Reason (April 2022), 31. Boldface emphasis added.

This is a horrible situation and a truly stupendously asinine problem. The blindingly obvious policy solution here is liberty — liberal and forgiving, totally unlicensed, unregulated, and unfettered economic freedom. The most likely practical strategy here is still countereconomic direct action.

If you’re a reformist, then go ahead and push whatever you push to try and vote in simpler, more just and more inclusive measures that will strip out that goddamned mess of a legalization law. But really, I think, after decades of voting and legislating and legalizing and licensing, it’s still the case that electoral politics is at the very best a lagging indicator for radical changes that happened long ago in culture and in society; in the numerical supermajority of cases California’s nonviolent drug users and dealers continue to find that the best way to make a change is not to jump into the politico-legalized system, but just to walk away from the political forum, to a different corner of the agora.

See also.

  • GT 2020-01-16: Listening To Weed the People, Latino USA:

    Obviously, no matter what ends up happening here, it’s hard to deny that the situation now — whatever its flaws — is not as bad as the situation that proceeded liberalization; obviously, nobody should want a halt to the process or a return to Drug War policing. But there’s also a sort of Against Legalization point that needs to be made here — about the effects that unsurprisingly, naturally occur when liberalization is only allowed to happen when and where it can be refracted through an elaborate, expensive, in some ways highly conservative regulatory regime for permitting and controlling the sale of weed to willing customers — something which, need we recall, is really just fine, and does not actually need to be controlled by the state, and should never have been treated as a crime in the first place.

    The city government in Oakland has approached the issue by trying to manipulate the issuing of permits — by implementing a priority queue that’s explicitly intended to benefit racial minorities, and operationally designed in favor granting licenses more quickly to people who had been arrested for drug crimes and people from neighborhoods where a lot of other people were arrested for drug crimes. But what if the permits themselves — and the drive to maintain social and economic control behind those permits — are part of the problem? . . .

    . . . [A] whole lot of black and Latino people have been victimized by the racial politics and the police violence of the drug war. The state owes them reparations for the years of damage that it has done. And the way they’ve tried to go about legalization risks excluding many of them from a market where — despite the risks and the costs and the violence unjustly inflicted on them under Prohibition — they had at least made something of a living up to now. But the best thing to do is not to try to tweak the licensing scheme to favor a different class of legal weed dealer; it’s to get rid of the restrictions and licensing entirely — to let as many people as possible enter the legal weed market, with a minimum of interference or monitoring by police, city governments and state regulators.

    — Rad Geek, GT 2020-01-16: Listening To Weed the People, Latino USA

  • GT 2010-01-27: The State of the Debate # 2: Against Legalization

    … And that’s why I’m against legalization schemes. For decriminalization, yes, of course; but against this kind of cockamamie tax-and-regulate license-monopoly scheme, carried out in the name of exposing yet another good to government control.

    It’s also why I’m against relying on electoral politics as a means of social change. When the political debate is constrained to the one side, who argue for arresting harmless potheads and locking them in cages, even though they think it is a bad idea, simply because their conscience demands absolute submission to the will of the United States federal government; and the other side, who think that marijuana ought to be legalized *so that the government can use a tax-stamp scheme to more fully control people’s access to it — when, that is, the debate consists of two sides, each jockeying for position against the other to see which of them can package its policy proposals in the *most authoritarian** terms — when, I say, the political debate is constrained to those kind of options, it’s time to start looking for a new forum.

    —Rad Geek, GT 2010-01-27: The State of the Debate # 2: Against Legalization

  • GT 2010-02-04: Against legalization (cont’d):

    There ain’t nothing wrong with illegality that can’t be fixed with more extralegal grassroots social organization.

    Don’t legalize; organize.

    —Rad Geek, GT 2010-02-04: Against legalization (cont’d)

  1. [1][In One giant French kiss wrapped in money: Cannabis magnate admits bribing San Luis Obispo County supervisor, Matthew Ormseth, July 29, 2021. –R.G.]
  2. [2]Including chickenshit requirements on everything from your business plan to the storefront you occupy to the kinds of vans that you use to deliver your totally legal weed. Here’s Shackford, on pp. 30ff: Cannabis entrepreneurs who survive t licensing gauntlet still have to deal with complicated, burdensome, and expensive regulations imposed by two levels of government. Fresno, for example, requires more than $8,000 in application fees from those vying for the small number of licenses being distributed, and the eligibility process requires applicants to include six separate plans describing different components of their proposed business’s operational models. Each of those plans have a dozen or more city-mandated information requirements. Meanwhile in Los Angeles’s social equity program, Applicants needed to secure a property to qualify, Jain [Hirsh Jain, chair of the Los Angeles Marijuana Chamber of Commerce] notes. Some had to take loans and were paying rent for storefronts. It bankrupted some applicants and made sure only the most well-capitalized could participate. Not exactly a winning model for lifting up the poor.
Anticopyright. All pages written 1996–2024 by Rad Geek. Feel free to reprint if you like it. This machine kills intellectual monopolists.